How is the demand of a commodity by changes in the prices of other commodities?

This is a preview. Log in to get access

Journal Information

The International Economic Review was established in 1960 by two of the most active and acclaimed scholars in the economics profession: Michio Morishima, who was then at Osaka University's Institute of Social Economic Research (ISER), and Lawrence R. Klein, who was then at the University of Pennsylvania's Wharton School and Department of Economics. The goal was to provide a forum for modern quantitative economics. From its inception, the journal has tried to stimulate economic analysis by publishing cutting-edge research in many areas, including econometrics, macroeconomics, theory, and applied economics. The International Economic Review initiates the use of this electronic medium as a continuation of our mission to promote and disseminate economic research. The IER is now run as a non-profit joint academic venture between Osaka University's Institute of Social and Economic Research and the University of Pennsylvania's Department of Economics. IER Website: http://www.econ.upenn.edu/ier Contact: Michele Souli JSTOR provides a digital archive of the print version of International Economic Review. The electronic version of International Economic Review is available at http://www.interscience.wiley.com. Authorized users may be able to access the full text articles at this site.

Publisher Information

Wiley is a global provider of content and content-enabled workflow solutions in areas of scientific, technical, medical, and scholarly research; professional development; and education. Our core businesses produce scientific, technical, medical, and scholarly journals, reference works, books, database services, and advertising; professional books, subscription products, certification and training services and online applications; and education content and services including integrated online teaching and learning resources for undergraduate and graduate students and lifelong learners. Founded in 1807, John Wiley & Sons, Inc. has been a valued source of information and understanding for more than 200 years, helping people around the world meet their needs and fulfill their aspirations. Wiley has published the works of more than 450 Nobel laureates in all categories: Literature, Economics, Physiology or Medicine, Physics, Chemistry, and Peace. Wiley has partnerships with many of the world’s leading societies and publishes over 1,500 peer-reviewed journals and 1,500+ new books annually in print and online, as well as databases, major reference works and laboratory protocols in STMS subjects. With a growing open access offering, Wiley is committed to the widest possible dissemination of and access to the content we publish and supports all sustainable models of access. Our online platform, Wiley Online Library (wileyonlinelibrary.com) is one of the world’s most extensive multidisciplinary collections of online resources, covering life, health, social and physical sciences, and humanities.

Video transcript

We've talked a little bit about the law of demand which tells us all else equal, if we raise the price of a product, then the quantity demanded for that product will go down. Common sense. If we lower the price, than the quantity demanded will go up, and we'll see a few special cases for this. But what I want to do in this video is focus on these other things that we've been holding equal, the things that allow us to make this statement, that allow us to move along this curve, and think about if we were to change one of those things, that we were otherwise considering equal, how does that change the actual curve? How does that actually change the whole quantity demanded price relationship? And so the first of these that I will focus on, the first is the price of competing products. So if you assume that the price of-- actually I shouldn't say competing products, I'll say the price of related products, because we'll see that they're not competing. The price of related products is one of the things that we're assuming is constant when we, it's beheld equal when we show this relationship. We're assuming that these other things aren't changing. Now, what would happen if these things changed? Well, imagine we have, say, other ebooks-- books is price-- price goes up. The price of other ebooks go up. So what will that do to our price quantity demanded relationship? If other ebooks prices go up, now all of a sudden, my ebook, regardless of what price point we're at, at any of the price points, my ebook is going to look more desirable. At $2, it's more likely that people will want it, because the other stuff's more expensive. At $4 more people will want it, at $6 more people will want it, $8 more people will want it, at $10 more people will want it. So if this were to happen, that would actually shift the entire demand curve to the right. So it would start to look something like this. That is scenario one. And these other ebooks, we can call them substitutes for my product. So this right over here, these other ebooks, these are substitutes. People might say, oh, you know, that other book looks kind of comparable, if one is more expensive or one is cheaper, maybe I'll read one or the other. So in order to make this statement, in order to stay along this curve, we have to assume that this thing is constant. If this thing changes, this is going to move the curve. If other ebooks prices go up, it'll probably shift our curve to the right. If other ebooks prices go down, that will shift our entire curve to the left. So this is actually changing our demand. It's changing our whole relationship. So it's shifting demand to the right. So let me write that. So this is going to shift demand. So the entire relationship, demand, to the right. I really want to make sure that you have this point clear. When we hold everything else equal, we're moving along a given demand curve. We're essentially saying the demand, the price quantity demanded relationship, is held constant, and we can pick a price and we'll get a certain quantity demanded. We're moving along the curve. If we change one of those things, we might actually shift the curve. We'll actually change this demand schedule, which will change this curve. Now, there other related products, they don't just have to be substitutes. So, for example, let's think about scenario two. Or maybe the price of a Kindle goes up. Let me write this this way. Kindle's price goes up. Now, the Kindle is not a substitute. People don't either buy an ebook or they won't either buy my ebook or a Kindle. Kindle is a compliment. You actually need a Kindle or an iPad or something like it in order to consume my ebook. So this right over here is a complement. So if a complement's price becomes more expensive, and this is one of the things people might use to buy my book, then it would actually, for any given price, lower the quantity demanded. So in this situation, if my book is $2, since fewer people are going to have Kindles, or since maybe they used some of their money already to buy the Kindle, they're going to have less to buy my book or just fewer people will have the Kindle, for any given price is going to lower the quantity demanded. And so it'll essentially will shift, it'll change the entire demand curve will shift the demand curve to the left. So this right over here is scenario two. And you could imagine the other way, if the Kindle's price went down, then that would shift my demand curve to the right. If the price of substitutes went down, then that would shift my entire curve to the left. So you can think about all the scenarios, and actually I encourage you to. Think about drawing yourself, think about for products, that could be an ebook or could be some other type of product, and think about what would happen. Well, one, think about what the related products are, the substitutes and potentially complements, and then think about what happen as those prices change. And always keep in mind the difference between demand, which is this entire relationship, the entire curve that we can move along if we hold everything else equal and only change price, and quantity demanded, which is a particular quantity for our particular price holding everything else equal.

How is the demand of a commodity affected by changes in the prices of other commodities?

The law of supply and demand combines two fundamental economic principles describing how changes in the price of a resource, commodity, or product affect its supply and demand. As the price increases, supply rises while demand declines. Conversely, as the price drops supply constricts while demand grows.

How does price of the commodity affect demand?

(Car and Petrol) When the prices of the complementary goods rise, the demand for the given commodity falls and vice versa. For example, if the price of petrol rises, the demand for cars falls.